Skip to main content

Fuzzy games with a countable space of actions and applications to systems of generalized quasi-variational inequalities

Abstract

We introduce an abstract fuzzy economy (generalized fuzzy game) model with a countable space of actions, and we study the existence of fuzzy equilibrium. As application, we prove the existence of solutions for the systems of generalized quasi-variational inequalities with random fuzzy mappings, defined in this paper. Our results bring novelty to the current literature by considering random fuzzy mappings whose values are fuzzy sets over complete countable metric spaces.

1 Introduction

The classical abstract economy (or generalized game) model as formalized by Borglin and Keiding [1] or Shafer and Sonnenschein [2] consists of a finite set of agents, each characterized by certain constraints and preferences, described by correspondences. This model has played a central role in the study of the economies considered by Arrow and Debreu [3], and it has been generalized in many directions during the last decades. Kim and Lee [4] proved that the theory of fuzzy sets, initiated by Zadeh [5], has become a good framework for studying the equilibrium existence in the case of generalized games when the constraints or preferences are imprecise due to the agents’ behavior. These authors proved the first theorems related to this topic. For newer results, the reader should refer, for instance, to [68].

The purpose of this paper is twofold. Firstly, it extends the study of the abstract economy model with private information and a countable set of actions defined by the author (see [9]) in the fuzzy setting, by taking into account those situations in which the agents may have partial control over the actions they choose. Special attention is paid to the existence of fuzzy equilibrium. The uncertainties derived by the individual character of the agents in election situations are described with the help of fuzzy random mappings, as defined by Huang [10]. Secondly, the theorem regarding the existence of fuzzy equilibrium for the fuzzy games with countable action sets is applied to prove the existence of solutions for the systems of generalized quasi-equilibrium inequalities with random fuzzy mappings, which we introduce. The present work is motivated and inspired by the research going on in this field. We mention that Chang and Zhu [11] are the ones who first introduced the concept of variational inequalities for fuzzy mappings. Since then several classes of variational inequalities in the deterministic and fuzzy setting have been studied. For example, we quote Noor [12], Park and Jeong [13] and Ding and Park [14]. The random variational inequalities have been considered and studied recently (see, for instance, [1519]). The results of this paper, including the ones derived in the non-fuzzy setting, are brand new and have not been reported in literature previously.

The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Some notational and terminological conventions are given in the following section, then Section 3.1 introduces the model of an abstract fuzzy economy with private information and a countable space of actions. The main result concerns the existence of fuzzy equilibrium, stated in Section 3.2. Section 4.1 defines new types of systems of random quasi-variational inequalities with random fuzzy mappings. The existence of their solutions is proved in Section 4.2. Section 4.3 contains the results in a non-fuzzy setting, shown as consequences of the previously obtained theorems. Finally, Section 5 presents the conclusions of our research.

2 Notation and definitions

The fuzzy set theory, introduced by Zadeh [5], is a framework very much used in mathematical economics. The fuzzy sets are characterized by the fact that the degree of membership of any of its elements can be any number in the unit interval [0,1], as opposed to the fact that only the binary pair {0,1} can give candidates for the degree of membership of the elements of crisp sets.

We present below some notions related to this theory.

If Y is a topological space, then a function A from Y into [0,1] is called a fuzzy set on Y (see Chang [20]). The family of all fuzzy sets on Y is denoted by F(Y). If X and Y are topological spaces, then a mapping P:XF(Y) is called a fuzzy mapping. If P is a fuzzy mapping, then for each xX, P(x) is a fuzzy set on Y and P(x)(y)[0,1], yY is called the degree of membership of y in P(x). Let AF(Y), a[0,1], then the set ( A ) a ={yY:A(y)>a} is called a strong a-cut set of the fuzzy set A.

For the reader’s convenience, we review a few basic definitions and results concerning the measurability of correspondences.

Let (T,T) be a measurable space, Y be a topological space and F:T 2 Y be a correspondence. F is weakly measurable if F l (A)T for each open subset A of Y (the lower inverse F l , also called the weak inverse, of a subset A of Y is defined by F l (A)={xA:F(x)A}). F is measurable if F l (A)T for each closed subset A of Y. If (T,T) is a measurable space, Y is a countable set and F:T 2 Y is a correspondence, then F is measurable if for each yY, F 1 (y)={tT:yF(t)} is T-measurable. For a correspondence F:T 2 Y from a measurable space into a metrizable space, we have that if F is measurable, then it is also weakly measurable and if F is compact valued and weakly measurable, it is measurable. Different aspects on measurability of correspondences can be found, for instance, in [2124].

Random fuzzy mappings have been defined in order to model random mechanisms generating imprecisely-valued data which can be properly described by using fuzzy sets.

Let Y be a topological space, F(Y) be a collection of all fuzzy sets over Y and (Ω,F) be a measurable space. A fuzzy mapping P:ΩF(Y) is said to be measurable (see [25]) if for any given a[0,1], ( P ( ) ) a :Ω 2 Y is a measurable set-valued mapping. A fuzzy mapping P:ΩF(Y) is said to have a measurable graph if for any given a[0,1], the set-valued mapping ( P ( ) ) a :Ω 2 Y has a measurable graph. A fuzzy mapping P:Ω×XF(Y) is called a random fuzzy mapping if, for any given xX, P(,x):ΩF(Y) is a measurable fuzzy mapping.

3 Fuzzy equilibrium existence for abstract fuzzy economies with private information and a countable set of actions

A new direction in mathematical economics and in game theory concerns the fact that the uncertainties which characterize the individual feature of agents’ decisions, involved in different economic activities, must be included in the mathematical models. The uncertainties can be described using random fuzzy mappings. Thus the framework of fuzziness has become part of the language of applied mathematics.

This section is devoted to defining a new model of abstract fuzzy economy with private information and a countable set of actions and to proving the existence of fuzzy equilibrium. The model is an extension of the classical deterministic models of abstract economy due to Borglin and Keiding [1] or Shafer and Sonnenschein [2]. They considered only a finite set of agents. This model generalizes the one defined in [9] by considering the fuzzy setting. It is different from other models of abstract fuzzy economy with private information existent in the literature (see [26] or [27]), because the values of random fuzzy constraint mappings and of random fuzzy preference mappings are fuzzy sets over countable complete metric spaces and the theory of the distributions of correspondences is used. Other models introduced by the author and based on measurability requirements are those from [7, 28, 29].

3.1 The model of an abstract fuzzy economy with private information

The abstract economy is an intermediate model which makes the connection between the Nash-type general ones, which describe the general competitive situations, without being specific (see [30]) and the one of Arrow-Debreu, which belongs to the economic field and therefore is a specialized model (see [3]).

We define a new model of an abstract fuzzy economy with private information and a countable set of actions.

Definition 1 An abstract fuzzy economy (or a generalized fuzzy game) with private information and a countable space of actions is defined as follows:

Γ= ( ( ( Ω i , Z i ) i I , μ ) , ( S i , X i , ( A i , a i ) , ( P i , p i ) ) i I ) ,

where I is a non-empty finite set (the set of agents) and:

  1. (a)

    X i : Ω i F( S i ) is the action (strategy) fuzzy mapping of agent i;

  2. (b)

    A i : Ω i × D X , z F( S i ) is a random fuzzy mapping (the constraint mapping of agent i);

  3. (c)

    P i : Ω i × D X , z F( S i ) is a random fuzzy mapping (the preference mapping of agent i);

  4. (d)

    a i : D X , z (0,1] is a random fuzzy constraint function and p i : D X , z (0,1] is a random fuzzy preference function;

  5. (e)

    z i (0,1] is such that for all ( ω i , h g ) Ω i × D X , z , ( A i ( ω i , h g ) ) a i ( h g ) ( X i ( ω i ) ) z i and ( P i ( ω , h g ) ) p i ( h g ) ( X i ( ω ) ) z i .

Now, we will explain the elements of the model and we will also give an interpretation.

I is a non-empty finite set (the set of agents). For each iI, the space of actions S i is a countable complete metric space and ( Ω i , Z i ) is a measurable space. (Ω,F) is the product measurable space ( i I Ω i , i I Z i ), and μ is a probability measure on (Ω,F). For a point ω=( ω 1 ,, ω n )Ω, we define the coordinate projections τ i (ω)= ω i . The random mapping τ i (ω) is interpreted as player i’s private information related to his action.

We also denote, for each iI, Meas( Ω i , S i ) the set of measurable mappings from ( Ω i , Z i ) to S i . An element g i of Meas( Ω i , S i ) is called a pure strategy for player i. A pure strategy profile g is an n-vector function ( g 1 , g 2 ,, g n ) that specifies a pure strategy for each player.

We suppose that there exists a fuzzy mapping X i : Ω i F ( S i ) such that each agent i can choose an action from ( X i ( ω i ) ) z i S i for each ω i Ω i . The function g i : Ω i S i is said to be a selection of ( X i ( ) ) z i if g i ( ω i ) ( X i ( ω i ) ) z i for every ω i Ω i .

D ( X i ( ) ) z i is the set {(μ τ i 1 ) g i 1 : g i  is a measurable selection of  ( X i ( ) ) z i } and D X , z := i I D ( X i ( ) ) z i .

For each iI, we denote h g i =(μ τ i 1 ) g i 1 , where g i is a measurable selection of ( X i ( ) ) z i and h g =( h g 1 , h g 2 ,, h g n ).

For each agent i, the constraints and the preferences are described by using the random fuzzy mappings A i respectively P i . In the state of the world ωΩ= i I Ω i , the number P i ( ω i , h g )(y)[0,1] associated to ( h g ,y) can be interpreted as the degree of intensity with which y is preferred to g i ( ω i ) or the degree of truth with which y is preferred to g i ( ω i ). We also can see the value A i ( ω i , h g )(y)[0,1], associated to ( h g ,y), as the belief of the player i that in the state ω i he can choose yY. The element z i is the action level in each state of the world, a i ( h g ) expresses the perceived degree of feasibility of the strategy g and p i ( h g ) represents the preference level of the strategy g.

The notion of fuzzy equilibrium for this model is introduced below. It generalizes the deterministic definition of equilibrium we owe to Shafer and Sonnenschein [2] and the stochastic one proposed by the author in [9].

Definition 2 A fuzzy equilibrium for Γ is defined as a strategy profile g =( g 1 , g 2 ,, g n ) i I Meas( Ω i , S i ) such that for each iI:

  1. (1)

    g i ( ω i ) ( A i ( ω i , h g ) ) a i ( h g ) for each ω i Ω i ;

  2. (2)

    ( A i ( ω i , h g ) ) a i ( h g ) ( P i ( ω i , h g ) ) p i ( h g ) =ϕ for each ω i Ω i .

3.2 Existence of fuzzy equilibrium for abstract fuzzy economies with a countable set of actions

This subsection is designed to establish the existence of fuzzy equilibrium of the abstract fuzzy economies. The assumptions concern the measurability and the upper semicontinuity of correspondences which define the model.

The following definitions and properties are essential tools used to prove the existence of fuzzy equilibrium.

Let X, Y be topological spaces and F:X 2 Y be a correspondence. F is said to be upper semicontinuous if for each xX and each open set V in Y with F(x)V, there exists an open neighborhood U of x in X such that F(y)V for each yU.

Lemma 1 [19]

Let X and Y be two topological spaces and let A be an open subset of X. Suppose that F 1 :X 2 Y , F 2 :X 2 Y are upper semicontinuous such that F 2 (x) F 1 (x) for all xA. Then the correspondence F:X 2 Y defined by

F(x)= { F 1 ( x ) , if  x A , F 2 ( x ) , if  x A

is also upper semicontinuous.

We follow Yu and Zhang [31]. Let Y be a countable complete metric space, (T,T,λ) be an atomless probability space and F:T 2 Y be a measurable correspondence. The function f:TY is said to be a selection of F if f(t)F(t) for λ-almost tT. Let us denote D F ={λ f 1 :f is a measurable selection of F}.

We will present some regular properties of D F , also obtained by Yu and Zhang [31]. The next lemmata state the convexity and the compactness of D F for any correspondence F.

Lemma 2 [31]

Let Y be a countable complete metric space, (T,T,λ) be an atomless probability space and F:T 2 Y be a measurable correspondence. Then D F is non-empty and convex in the space M(Y) - the space of probability measures on Y, endowed with the topology of weak convergence.

Lemma 3 [31]

Let Y be a countable complete metric space, (T,T,λ) be an atomless probability space and F:T 2 Y be a measurable correspondence. If F is compact valued, then D F is compact in M(Y).

Lemma 4 [31]

Let X be a metric space, (T,T,λ) be an atomless probability space, Y be a countable complete metric space and F:T×X 2 Y be a correspondence. Let us assume that for any fixed x in X, F(,x) (also denoted by F x ) is a compact-valued measurable correspondence, and for each fixed tT, F(t,) is upper semicontinuous on X. Also, let us assume that there exists a compact-valued correspondence H:T×X 2 Y such that F(t,x)H(t) for all t and x. Then D F x is upper semicontinuous on X.

We will also need the Kuratowski-Ryll-Nardzewski selection theorem in order to prove our main result.

Theorem 1 (Kuratowski-Ryll-Nardzewski selection theorem) [32]

A weakly measurable correspondence with non-empty closed values from a measurable space into a Polish space admits a measurable selector.

Let us denote λ=( λ 1 , λ 2 ,, λ n ) D X , z .

Theorem 2 is our main result in this paper. It generalizes Theorem 3 in [9] by considering the fuzzy framework. We emphasize that our arguments to the existence of fuzzy equilibrium are different from the approaches used in literature, since the modeling of the private information and the countable space of actions assumes a new setting. The proof relies in particular on the Kuratowski-Ryll-Nardzewski selection theorem and on the Fan fixed point theorem. The possible applications of this result may concern the aspects of the economies or markets in which countable aspects matter.

Theorem 2 Let Γ=(( ( Ω i , Z i ) i I ,μ), ( S i , X i , ( A i , a i ) , ( P i , p i ) ) i I ) be an abstract fuzzy economy, with private information and countable spaces of actions, where μ is atomless and for each iI:

  1. (a)

    the correspondence ( X i ( ) ) z i : Ω i 2 S i is compact valued;

  2. (b)

    for each λ D X , z , the correspondence ( A i ( , λ ) ) a i ( λ ) : Ω i 2 S i is measurable and, for all ω i Ω i , the correspondence ( A i ( ω i , ) ) a i ( ) : D X , z 2 S i is upper semicontinuous with non-empty compact values;

  3. (c)

    for each λ D X , z , the correspondence ( P i ( , λ ) ) p i ( λ ) : Ω i 2 S i is measurable and, for all ω i Ω i , the correspondence ( P i ( ω i , ) ) p i ( ) : D X , z 2 S i is upper semicontinuous with non-empty compact values;

  4. (d)

    for each ω i Ω i and each g i I Meas( Ω i , S i ), g i ( ω i ) ( P i ( ω i , h g ) ) p i ( h g ) ;

  5. (e)

    the set U i ω i :={λ D X , z : ( A i ( ω i , λ ) ) a i ( λ ) P i ( ( ω i , λ ) ) p i ( λ ) =} is open in D X , z for each ω i Ω i .

Then there exists g i I Meas( Ω i , S i ) an equilibrium for Γ.

Proof The fixed point approach can be effectively exploited. To do this, we will construct several correspondences.

Let iI be fixed.

Let us denote

U i : = { ( ω i , λ ) Ω i × D X , z : ( A i ( ω i , λ ) ) a i ( λ ) P i ( ( ω i , λ ) ) p i ( λ ) = } and U i ω i : = { λ D X , z : ( A i ( ω i , λ ) ) a i ( λ ) P i ( ( ω i , λ ) ) p i ( λ ) = } .

Let us define F i : Ω i × D X , z 2 S i by

F i ( ω i , λ ) = { ( A i ( ω i , λ ) ) a i ( λ ) ( P i ( ω i , λ ) ) p i ( λ ) if  ( ω i , λ ) U i , ( A i ( ω i , λ ) ) a i ( λ ) if  ( ω i , λ ) U i and Φ : D X , z 2 D X , z , Φ ( λ ) = i I D F i ( λ )

for each λ D X , z , where D F i (λ)={ h g i =(μ τ i 1 ) g i 1 : g i  is a measurable selection of  F i (,λ)}.

We will apply the Ky Fan fixed point theorem to the correspondence Φ and we will obtain the existence of a fixed point, which will be the equilibrium point for the abstract economy Γ. For this purpose, we check the properties of the involved sets and the correspondences F i and Φ.

Firstly, we note that D ( X i ( ) ) z i is non-empty and convex according to Lemma 2 and it is compact according to Lemma 3. Consequently, the set D X , z is also non-empty, compact and convex.

According to assumptions (b) and (c), the correspondence F i has non-empty and compact values and it is measurable with respect to Ω i . Assumption (e) implies that the set U i ω i is open in D X , z and assumptions (b) and (c) imply that for all ω i Ω i , ( A i ( ω i , ) ) a i ( ) , ( P i ( ω i , ) ) p i ( ) : D ( X ( ) ) z 2 S i are upper semicontinuous; therefore, we can apply Lemma 1 to assert that F i is upper semicontinuous with respect to λ D X , z .

Furthermore, for each λ D X , z , D F i (λ) is non-empty, convex and compact. The non-emptiness of each D F i (λ) is implied by the existence of a measurable selection from the correspondence F i , according to the Kuratowski-Ryll-Nardzewski selection theorem. Lemma 2 and Lemma 3 also assure the convexity and compactness of the set D F i (λ), where λ D X , z .

According to Lemma 4, the correspondence D F i is upper semicontinuous. Then the correspondence Φ is upper semicontinuous and has non-empty, compact and convex values. We have also proved that it is defined on a non-empty, convex and compact set. We can apply the Ky Fan fixed point theorem [33] to Φ, and we obtain that there exists a fixed point λ Φ( λ ). In particular, for each player i, λ i D F i ( λ ). From the definition of D F i ( λ ), we conclude that for each player i, there exists g i Meas( Ω i , S i ) such that g i is a selection of F i (, λ ) and h g i =(μ τ i 1 ) ( g i ) 1 = λ i . Let us denote h g =( h g 1 ,, h g n ).

We prove that g is an equilibrium for Γ. For each iI, because g i is a selection of F i (, h g 1 ,, h g n ), it follows that g i ( ω i ) ( A i ( ω i , h g ) ) a i ( h g ) ( P i ( ω i , h g ) ) p i ( h g ) if ( ω i , h g ) U i or g i ( ω i ) ( A i ( ω i , h g ) ) a i ( h g ) if ( ω i , h g ) U i .

According to assumption (d), it follows that g i ( ω i ) ( P i ( ω i , h g ) ) p i ( h g ) for each ω i Ω i . Then g i ( ω i ) ( A i ( ω i , h g ) ) a i ( h g ) and ( ω i , h g ) U i . This is equivalent to the fact that g i ( ω i ) ( A i ( ω i , h g ) ) a i ( h g ) and ( A i ( ω i , h g ) ) a i ( h g ) P i ( ω i , h g ) p i ( h g ) = for each ω i Ω i . Consequently, g =( g 1 , g 2 ,, g n ) is an equilibrium for Γ. □

4 Random quasi-variational inequalities with random fuzzy mappings

The techniques to prove the equilibrium existence for the abstract economies are often used to solve other problems related to this field, especially the variational inequalities, mini-max theorems, some classes of quasi-equilibrium problems and the existence of equilibrium for the exchange economies. A number of applications of the results from Section 3 can be further obtained. We focus here on the definition of a new type of systems of quasi-variational inequalities with random fuzzy mappings whose values are fuzzy sets over complete countable metric spaces and on the proof of the existence of their solutions.

The theory of variational inequality considers a large spectrum of interesting and important tools used in various fields of mathematics, physics, economics and engineering sciences.

4.1 New types of systems of generalized quasi-variational inequalities

Motivated by the large literature developed since Chang and Zhu [11] introduced the concept of variational inequalities for fuzzy mappings and since Noor and Elsanousi [17] defined the notion of a random variational inequality, we also propose new types of systems of generalized quasi-variational inequalities, which seem to be very welcome in this context.

We will use the same setting as in Section 3.

For each iI, let S i be a countable complete metric space. Let A i : Ω i × D X F( S i ) be a fuzzy mapping, and let a i : D X (0,1] be a fuzzy function. Let ψ i : Ω i × D X × S i R{,+}.

Now, we introduce a new type of systems of generalized quasi-variational inequalities as follows.

  1. (1)

    Find λ D X such that for every iI and for all ω i Ω i :

  2. (i)

    λ i ( ω i ) ( A i ( ω i , λ ) ) a i ( λ ) ;

  3. (ii)

    sup y i ( A i ( ( ω i , λ ) ) ) a i ( λ ) ψ i ( ω i , λ , y i )0,

where ( A i x ) a i ( x ) ={z Y i : A i x (z) a i ( x )}.

We note that (1) extends a special deterministic case of quasi-variational inequalities considered by several authors (e.g. see Yuan [19] and the references therein) and the random quasi-variational inequalities studied by Tan and Yuan in [18] or Yuan (see [34] and the references therein).

If A i : Ω i × D X 2 S i is a classical correspondence and ψ i : Ω i × D X × S i R{,+}, then we get the following variational inequality as a special case of (1).

(2) Find λ D X such that for every iI and for all ω i Ω i :

(i) λ i ( ω i ) A i ( ω i , λ );

(ii) sup y i A i ( ω i , λ ) ψ i ( ω i , λ , y i )0.

Finally, we define the following system of generalized quasi-variational inequalities, in case that for each iI, S i is a countable completely metrizable topological vector space, S i is the dual space of S i , A i : Ω i × D X F( S i ), G i : Ω i × S i F( S i ) are fuzzy mappings and a i : D X (0,1], g i : S i (0,1] are fuzzy functions.

  1. (3)

    Find λ D X such that for every iI and for all ω i Ω i :

  2. (i)

    λ i ( ω i ) ( A i ( ω i , λ ) ) a i ( λ ) ;

  3. (ii)

    sup y i ( A i ( ω i , λ ) ) a i ( λ ) sup v ( G i ( ω i , y i ) ) g i ( y i ) Rev, λ i ( ω i ) y i 0,

where the real part of pairing between S i and S i is denoted by Rev,x for each v S i and x S i .

If A i : Ω i × D X 2 S i and G i : Ω i × S i 2 S i are classical correspondences, then we get the following variational inequality.

  1. (4)

    Find λ D X such that for every iI and for all ω i Ω i :

  2. (i)

    λ ( ω i ) A i ( ω i , λ );

  3. (ii)

    sup y i A i ( ω i , λ ) sup v G i ( ω i , y i ) Rev, λ i ( ω i ) y i 0.

System (4) extends a special deterministic case of quasi-variational inequalities considered by several authors (e.g. see Yuan [35] and the references therein) and the random quasi-variational inequalities studied by Yuan (see [19] and the references therein).

Our systems of quasi-variational inequalities are different from the existent ones in literature in the following aspects: random fuzzy mappings are considered and their values are fuzzy sets over complete countable metric spaces.

4.2 Existence of the solutions of systems of generalized quasi-variational inequalities with random fuzzy mappings

In this subsection, we establish new results concerning the existence of the systems of generalized random quasi-variational inequalities with random fuzzy mappings. The proofs are based mainly on the theorem of fuzzy equilibrium existence for the abstract fuzzy economy.

In order to obtain the theorems in the next subsections, we set here the following common conditions.

Let I be a non-empty and finite set. For each iI, S i is a countable complete metric space and ( Ω i , Z i ) is a measurable space. Let (Ω,Z) be a product measurable space ( i I Ω i , i I Z i ) and let μ be an atomless probability measure on (Ω,Z). For each iI, the correspondence X i : Ω i F( S i ) is measurable.

This is our first theorem.

Theorem 3 Suppose that the following conditions are satisfied for each iI:

  1. (a)

    the correspondence ( X i ( ) ) z i : Ω i 2 S i has compact values;

  2. (b)

    for each λ D X , z , the correspondence ( A i ( , λ ) ) a i ( λ ) : Ω i 2 S i is measurable and, for all ω i Ω i , the correspondence ( A i ( ω i , ) ) a i ( ) : D X , z 2 S i is upper semicontinuous with non-empty compact values.

Let us assume that the mapping ψ i : Ω i × D X , z × S i R{,+} is such that:

  1. (c)

    λ{y S i : ψ i (ω,λ,y)>0}: D X , z 2 S i is upper semicontinuous with compact values on D X , z for each fixed ω i Ω i ;

  2. (d)

    λ i ( ω i ){y S i : ψ i ( ω i ,λ,y)>0} for each fixed ( ω i ,λ) Ω i × D X , z ;

  3. (e)

    for each ω i Ω i , {λ D X , z : α i ( ω i ,λ)>0} is weakly open in D X , z , where α i : Ω i × D X , z R is defined by

    α i ( ω i ,λ)= sup y ( A i ( ω i , λ ) ) a i ( λ ) ψ i ( ω i ,λ,y)for each ( ω i ,λ) Ω i × D X , z ;
  4. (f)

    { ω i : α i ( ω i ,λ)>0} Z i for each λ D X , z .

Then there exists λ D X , z such that for every iI and for every ω i Ω i :

  1. (i)

    λ i ( ω i ) ( A i ( ω i , λ ) ) a i ( λ ) ;

  2. (ii)

    sup y ( A i ( ω , λ ) ) a i ( λ ) ψ i ( ω i , λ ,y)0.

Proof For every iI, let P i : Ω i × D X , z F( S i ) and p i : D X , z (0,1] such that ( P i ( ω , λ ) ) p i ( λ ) ={y S i : ψ i ( ω i ,λ,y)>0} for each ( ω i ,λ) Ω i × D X , z .

We shall show that the abstract economy Γ=(( ( Ω i , Z i ) i I ,μ), ( S i , X i , ( A i , a i ) , ( P i , p i ) ) i I ) satisfies all the hypotheses of Theorem 2.

For this purpose, let us consider ω i Ω i .

According to (c), we have that λ ( P i ( ω i , λ ) ) p i ( λ ) : D X , z 2 S i is upper semicontinuous with non-empty values and according to (d), λ i ( ω i ) ( P i ( ω i , λ ) ) p i ( λ ) for each λ D X , z .

According to the definition of α i , we note that, for each ω i Ω i , {λ D X , z : ( A i ( ω i , λ ) ) a i ( λ ) ( P i ( ω i , λ ) ) p i ( λ ) }={λ D X , z : α i (ω,λ)>0} so that {λ D X , z : ( A i ( ω i , λ ) ) a i ( λ ) ( P i ( ω i , λ ) ) p i ( λ ) } is weakly open in D X , z by (e).

According to (b) and (f), it follows that for each λ D X , z , the correspondences ( A i ( , λ ) ) a i ( λ ) : Ω i 2 S i and ( P i ( ω i , λ ) ) p i ( λ ) : Ω i 2 S i are measurable.

Thus, the abstract fuzzy economy Γ=(( ( Ω i , Z i ) i I ,μ), ( S i , X i , ( A i , a i ) , ( P i , p i ) ) i I ) satisfies all the hypotheses of Theorem 2. Therefore, there exists λ D X , z such that for every iI and for every ω i Ω i :

λ i ( ω i ) ( A i ( ω i , λ ) ) a i ( λ ) and ( A i ( ω i , λ ) ) a i ( λ ) ( P i ( ω i , λ ) ) p i ( λ ) = ϕ ;

that is, there exists λ D X , z such that for every iI and for every ω i Ω i :

  1. (i)

    λ i (ω) ( A i ( ω , λ ) ) a i ( λ ) ;

  2. (ii)

    sup y ( A i ( ω i , λ ) ) a i ( λ ) ψ i ( ω i , λ ,y)0.

 □

Remark 1 The above theorem can be compared with Theorem 5 in [34] which states an existence result for the solutions of random quasi-variational inequalities in case that A i (ω,): i I X i 2 X i is upper semicontinuous for each ωΩ and iI.

If |I|=1, we obtain the following corollary.

Corollary 1 Let S be a countable complete metric space, (Ω,Z,μ) be a measure space, where μ is atomless. Suppose that the following conditions are satisfied:

  1. (a)

    the correspondence ( X ( ) ) z : Ω i 2 S has compact values;

  2. (b)

    for each λ D X , z , the correspondence ( A ( , λ ) ) a ( λ ) :Ω 2 S is measurable and, for all ωΩ, the correspondence ( A ( ω , ) ) a ( ) : D X , z 2 S is upper semicontinuous with non-empty compact values.

The mapping ψ:Ω× D X , z ×SR{,+} is such that:

  1. (c)

    λ{yY:ψ(ω,λ,y)>0}: D X , z 2 S is upper semicontinuous with compact values on D X , z for each fixed ωΩ;

  2. (d)

    λ(ω){yS:ψ(ω,λ,y)>0} for each fixed (ω,λ)Ω× D X , z ;

  3. (e)

    for each ωΩ, {λ D X , z :α(ω,λ)>0} is weakly open in D X , z , where α:Z× D X , z R is defined by

    α(ω,λ)= sup y ( A ( ω , λ ) ) a ( λ ) ψ(ω,λ,y)for each (ω,λ)Z× D X , z ;
  4. (f)

    {ω:α(ω,λ)>0}Z for each λ D X , z .

Then there exists λ D X , z such that and for every ωΩ:

  1. (i)

    λ (ω) ( A ( ω , λ ) ) a i ( λ ) ;

  2. (ii)

    sup y ( A ( ω , λ ) ) a ( λ ) ψ(ω, λ ,y)0.

As a consequence of Theorem 3, we prove the following Tan and Yuan’s type [18] system of generalized random quasi-variational inequalities with random fuzzy mappings.

Theorem 4 Suppose that the following conditions are satisfied for each iI:

  1. (a)

    the correspondence ( X i ( ) ) z i : Ω i 2 S i has compact values;

  2. (b)

    for each λ D X , z , the correspondence ( A i ( , λ ) ) a i ( λ ) : Ω i 2 S i is measurable and, for all ω i Ω i , the correspondence ( A i ( ω i , ) ) a i ( ) : D X , z 2 S i is upper semicontinuous with non-empty compact values.

G i : Ω i × S i F( S i ) and g i : S i (0,1] are such that:

  1. (c)

    for each fixed ( ω i ,y) Ω i × S i , λ{y S i : sup u ( G i ( ω i , y ) ) g i ( y ) Reu, λ i ( ω i )y>0}: D X , z 2 S i is upper semicontinuous with compact values;

  2. (d)

    for each fixed ω i Ω i , the set {λ D X , z : sup y ( A i ( ω i , λ ) ) a i ( λ ) sup u ( G i ( ω i , y ) ) g i ( y ) Reu, λ i ( ω i )y>0} is weakly open in D X , z ;

  3. (e)

    { ω i Ω i : sup u ( G i ( ω , y ) ) g i ( y ) Reu, λ i ( ω i )y>0} Z i for each λ D X , z .

Then there exists λ D X , z such that for every iI and for every ω i Ω i :

  1. (i)

    λ i ( ω i ) ( A i ( ω i , λ ) ) a i ( λ ) ;

  2. (ii)

    sup u ( G i ( ω i , y ) ) g i ( y ) Reu, λ i ( ω i )y0 for all y ( A i ( ω i , λ ) ) a i ( λ ) .

Proof Let us define ψ i : Ω i × D X , z × S i R{,+} by

ψ i ( ω i ,λ,y)= sup u ( G i ( ω i , y ) ) g i ( y ) Re u , λ i ( ω i ) y for each ( ω i ,λ,y) Ω i × D X , z × S i .

We have that λ i ( ω i ){y S i : ψ i ( ω i ,λ,y)>0} for each fixed ( ω i ,λ) Ω i × D X , z .

All the hypotheses of Theorem 3 are satisfied. According to Theorem 3, there exists λ D X , z such that for every iI and for every ω i Ω i :

λ i ( ω i ) ( A i ( ω i , λ ) ) a i ( λ ) and sup y ( A i ( ω i , λ ) ) a i ( λ ) sup u ( G i ( ω i , y ) ) g i ( y ) Re u , λ i ( ω i ) y 0 .

Similar to Corollary 1, a result can be reached in case that |I|=1. □

The following theorem is obtained as a particular case of Theorem 3.

Theorem 5 Suppose that the following conditions are satisfied for each iI:

  1. (a)

    the correspondence ( X i ( ) ) z i : Ω i 2 S i has compact values;

  2. (b)

    for each λ D X , z , the correspondence ( A i ( , λ ) ) a i ( λ ) : Ω i 2 S i is measurable and, for all ω i Ω i , the correspondence ( A i ( ω i , ) ) a i ( ) : D X , z 2 S i is upper semicontinuous with non-empty compact values.

Then there exists λ D X , z such that for every iI and for every ω i Ω i , λ i ( ω i ) ( A i ( ω i , λ ) ) a i ( λ ) .

If |I|=1, we obtain the following result.

Theorem 6 Let S be a countable complete metric space and let (Ω,Z,μ) be a measure space, where μ is atomless. Suppose that the following conditions are satisfied:

  1. (a)

    the correspondence ( X ( ) ) z :Ω 2 S has compact values;

  2. (b)

    for each λ D X , z , the correspondence ( A ( , λ ) ) a ( λ ) :Ω 2 S is measurable and, for all ωΩ, the correspondence ( A ( ω , ) ) a ( ) : D X , z 2 S is upper semicontinuous with non-empty compact values.

Then there exists λ D X , z such that, and for every ωΩ, λ (ω) ( A ( ω , λ ) ) a ( λ ) .

4.3 Classical systems of generalized quasi-variational inequalities

Several results concerning systems of generalized random quasi-variational inequalities in a non-fuzzy setting are obtained as consequences of the theorems stated in the last subsection. They are new and have not been reported in literature. We work under the same conditions which we have set at the beginning of Section 4.2. We present Theorem 7 as a consequence of Theorem 3.

Theorem 7 Suppose that the following conditions are satisfied for each iI:

  1. (a)

    the correspondence X i : Ω i 2 S i is measurable and has compact values;

  2. (b)

    the correspondence A i is such that for each λ D X , A i (,λ): Ω i 2 S i is measurable and, for all ω i Ω i , A i ( ω i ,): D X 2 S i is upper semicontinuous with non-empty compact values.

Let us assume that the mapping ψ i : Ω i × D X × S i R{,+} is such that:

  1. (c)

    λ{yY: ψ i (ω,λ,y)>0}: D X 2 S i is upper semicontinuous with compact values on D X for each fixed ω i Ω i ;

  2. (d)

    λ i ( ω i ){y S i : ψ i ( ω i ,λ,y)>0} for each fixed ( ω i ,λ) Ω i × D X ;

  3. (e)

    for each ω i Ω i , {λ D X : α i ( ω i ,λ)>0} is weakly open in D X , where α i : Ω i × D X R is defined by α i ( ω i ,λ)= sup y A i ( ω i , λ ) ψ i ( ω i ,λ,y) for each ( ω i ,λ) Ω i × D X ;

  4. (f)

    { ω i : α i ( ω i ,λ)>0} Z i for each λ D X .

Then there exists λ D X such that for every iI and for every ω i Ω i ,

  1. (i)

    λ i ( ω i ) A i ( ω i , λ );

  2. (ii)

    sup y A i ( ω , λ ) ψ i ( ω i , λ ,y)0.

The next theorem concerns the correspondences with values in complete countable metric spaces.

Theorem 8 Suppose that the following conditions are satisfied for each iI:

  1. (a)

    the correspondence X i : Ω i 2 S i is measurable with compact values;

  2. (b)

    for each λ D X , A i (,λ): Ω i 2 S i is measurable and, for all ω i Ω i , A i ( ω i ,): D X 2 S i is upper semicontinuous with non-empty compact values.

Then there exists λ D X such that for every iI and for every ω i Ω i , λ i ( ω i ) A i ( ω i , λ ).

5 Concluding remarks

The main object of this paper was to define a new model of an abstract fuzzy economy with private information and a countable set of actions and to prove the existence of fuzzy equilibrium under the upper semicontinuity assumptions. The uncertainties derived from the individual character of the agents in election situations have been described by using fuzzy random mappings. The techniques for proving the existence of equilibrium have been used to solve a new type of systems of quasi-variational inequalities with random fuzzy mappings which has been introduced in a special section.

Further attention is needed for the study of applications of the established results in the fuzzy economic field and fuzzy game theory. The methods and the setting in this paper can be adapted to solve other classes of generalized variational inequalities or quasi-equilibrium problems and they can especially be used in the general equilibrium theory.

References

  1. Borglin A, Keiding H: Existence of equilibrium actions and of equilibrium: a note on the ‘new’ existence theorem. J. Math. Econ. 1976, 3: 313–316. 10.1016/0304-4068(76)90016-1

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  2. Shafer W, Sonnenschein H: Equilibrium in abstract economies without ordered preferences. J. Math. Econ. 1975, 2: 345–348. 10.1016/0304-4068(75)90002-6

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  3. Arrow KJ, Debreu G: Existence of an equilibrium for a competitive economy. Econometrica 1954, 22: 265–290. 10.2307/1907353

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  4. Kim WK, Lee KH: Fuzzy fixed point and existence of equilibria of fuzzy games. J. Fuzzy Math. 1998, 6: 193–202.

    MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  5. Zadeh LA: Fuzzy sets. Inf. Control 1965, 8: 338–353. 10.1016/S0019-9958(65)90241-X

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  6. Kim WK, Lee KH: Generalized fuzzy games and fuzzy equilibria. Fuzzy Sets Syst. 2001, 122: 293–301. 10.1016/S0165-0114(00)00073-7

    Article  Google Scholar 

  7. Patriche M: Equilibrium in Games and Competitive Economies. The Publishing House of the Romanian Academy, Bucharest; 2011.

    MATH  Google Scholar 

  8. Wang L, Je CY, Huang N: The robustness of generalized abstract fuzzy economies in generalized convex spaces. Fuzzy Sets Syst. 2011, 176(1):56–63. 10.1016/j.fss.2011.03.010

    Article  Google Scholar 

  9. Patriche M: Existence of equilibrium for an abstract economy with private information and a countable space of actions. Mathem. Rep. 2013, 15(65)(3):233–242.

    MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  10. Huang NJ: Random generalized nonlinear variational inclusions for random fuzzy mappings. Fuzzy Sets Syst. 1999, 105(3):437–444. 10.1016/S0165-0114(97)00222-4

    Article  Google Scholar 

  11. Chang S-S, Zhu Y-G: On variational inequalities for fuzzy mappings. Fuzzy Sets Syst. 1989, 32: 359–367. 10.1016/0165-0114(89)90268-6

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  12. Noor MA: Variational inequalities for fuzzy mappings. III. Fuzzy Sets Syst. 2000, 110: 101–108. 10.1016/S0165-0114(98)00131-6

    Article  Google Scholar 

  13. Park JY, Lee SY, Jeong JU: Completely generalized strongly quasivariational inequalities for fuzzy mapping. Fuzzy Sets Syst. 2000, 110: 91–99. 10.1016/S0165-0114(98)00106-7

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  14. Ding X-P, Park J-Y: A new class of generalized non linear implicit quasi-variational inclusions with fuzzy mappings. J. Comput. Appl. Math. 2002, 138: 243–257. 10.1016/S0377-0427(01)00379-X

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  15. Gwinner J, Raciti F: On a class of random variational inequalities on random sets. Numer. Funct. Anal. Optim. 2006, 27(5–6):619–636. 10.1080/01630560600790819

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  16. Gwinner J, Raciti F: Some equilibrium problems under uncertainty and random variational inequalities. Ann. Oper. Res. 2012, 200: 299–319. 10.1007/s10479-012-1109-2

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  17. Noor MA, Elsanousi SA: Iterative algorithms for random variational inequalities. Panam. Math. J. 1993, 3: 39–50.

    MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  18. Tan K-K, Yuan GX-Z: Random equilibria of random generalized games with applications to non-compact random quasi-variational inequalities. Topol. Methods Nonlinear Anal. 1995, 5: 59–82.

    MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  19. Yuan XZ: The study of minimax inequalities and applications to economies and variational inequalities. Mem. Am. Math. Soc. 1988., 132: Article ID 625

    Google Scholar 

  20. Chang S-S: Coincidence theorems and variational inequalities for fuzzy mappings. Fuzzy Sets Syst. 1994, 61: 359–368. 10.1016/0165-0114(94)90178-3

    Article  Google Scholar 

  21. Croitoru A, Văideanu C: On pointwise measurability of multifunctions. An. Univ. ‘Ovidius’ Constanţa, Ser. Mat. 2009, 17: 69–76.

    Google Scholar 

  22. Croitoru A: Fuzzy integral of measurable multifunctions. Iran. J. Fuzzy Syst. 2012, 9(4):133–140.

    MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  23. Hu S, Papageorgiu NS I. In Handbook of Multivalued Analysis. Kluwer Academic, Dordrecht; 1997.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  24. Klein E, Thompson C: Theory of Correspondences. Wiley-Interscience, New York; 1984.

    MATH  Google Scholar 

  25. Uea NO, Kumam P: A generalized nonlinear random equations with random fuzzy mappings in uniformly smooth Banach spaces. J. Inequal. Appl. 2010., 2010: Article ID 728452 10.1155/2010/728452

    Google Scholar 

  26. Patriche M: Equilibrium of Bayesian fuzzy economies and quasi-variational inequalities with random fuzzy mappings. J. Inequal. Appl. 2013., 2013: Article ID 374 10.1186/1029-242X-2013-374

    Google Scholar 

  27. Patriche M: Bayesian abstract fuzzy economies, random quasi-variational inequalities with random fuzzy mappings and random fixed point theorems. Fuzzy Sets Syst. 2013. 10.1016/j.fss.2013.10.001

    Google Scholar 

  28. Patriche M: Bayesian abstract economy with a measure space of agents. Abstr. Appl. Anal. 2009., 2009: Article ID 523619

    Google Scholar 

  29. Patriche M: Bayesian abstract economies. Optimization 2011, 60(4):451–461. 10.1080/02331930903358830

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  30. Nash JF: Equilibrium points in n -person games. Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci. USA 1950, 36(1):48–49. 10.1073/pnas.36.1.48

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  31. Yu H, Zhang Z: Pure strategy equilibria in games with countable actions. J. Math. Econ. 2007, 43: 192–200. 10.1016/j.jmateco.2006.09.008

    Article  Google Scholar 

  32. Aliprantis CD, Border KC: Infinite Dimensional Analysis: A Hitchhiker’s Guide. Springer, Berlin; 1994.

    Book  MATH  Google Scholar 

  33. Fan K: Fixed-point and minimax theorems in locally convex topological linear spaces. Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci. USA 1952, 38: 121–126. 10.1073/pnas.38.2.121

    Article  Google Scholar 

  34. Yuan XZ: Non-compact random generalized games and random quasi-variational inequalities. J. Appl. Math. Stoch. Anal. 1994, 7(4):467–486. 10.1155/S1048953394000377

    Article  Google Scholar 

  35. Yuan XZ: Remarks on quasi-variational inequalities and fixed points in locally convex topological vector spaces. Appl. Math. Lett. 1997, 10(6):55–61. 10.1016/S0893-9659(97)00105-5

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Monica Patriche.

Additional information

Competing interests

The author declares that they have no competing interests.

Rights and permissions

Open Access This article is distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License (https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0), which permits use, duplication, adaptation, distribution, and reproduction in any medium or format, as long as you give appropriate credit to the original author(s) and the source, provide a link to the Creative Commons license, and indicate if changes were made.

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Patriche, M. Fuzzy games with a countable space of actions and applications to systems of generalized quasi-variational inequalities. Fixed Point Theory Appl 2014, 124 (2014). https://doi.org/10.1186/1687-1812-2014-124

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1186/1687-1812-2014-124

Keywords